The CJEU's Approach to Matters of Direct Taxation: A Critical Analysis

AuthorStephen Daly
PositionBCL (Int) LLM (Candidate) (Lond)
Pages1-17
[2013] COLR
1
THE CJEU’S APPROACH TO MATTERS OF DIRECT TAXATION: A CRITICAL
ANALYSIS
Stephen Daly*
ABSTRACT
Historically, the Court of Justice of the Eur opean Union has been eager to str ike down any
obstacle to trade which might compromise the fundamental freedoms and hinder progression
towards the ultimate goal of the Union; the cr eation of a Single Market. One obstacle which
the Court is not permitted to strike down per se is the Direct Taxation law of a Member State.
If such dir ect taxes however are discriminatory in nature, then the jurisdiction of the Court
will be engaged. The article outlines the competency of the CJEU in this matter and also the
merits of taking such an approach. Nonetheless, it will be demonstrated that the CJEU’s
approach to such matters has left much to be desired, although recent case-law suggests the
court may finally be progressing toward a more coherent a pproach.
A INTRODUCTION: THE NEED TO BREAK DOWN BARRIERS
At the time of writing, the European Union is in the midst of a ‘Eurozone’ debt crisis of
unprecedented proportions. The Member States are faced with two options. One possible
eventuality envisages the demise of the Union, with each State shouldering the burden of its
own national debt. As the various EU treaties did not foresee such an eventuality, there is
thusly no simple method of exiting the fiscal union which took so many years of preparatory
work to formulate. Moreover, the split would have disastrous consequences for the world
economy if the teetering countries such as Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Spain enter
bankruptcy.
1 The alternative is to further integrate European Economic markets in pursuit of
the ultimate goal of the EU, namely, the establishment of a single integrated market.2
One of the most prominent obstacles to such integration to date, and the creation of a single
market, is that of national direct taxation measures, an area in which Member States are
* BCL (Int) LLM (Candidate) (Lond).
1 Jordan Weissmann, ‘Eurogeddon A Worst Case Scenario Handbook for the European Debt Crisis’ ( The
Atlantic 12 June 2012)
scenario-handbook-for-the-european-debt-crisis/258368/> accessed 19 Febr uary 2013.
2 For support of this argument and an interesting analysis of the causes of the European crisis, See Matthias
Matthijs and Mark Blyth, ‘Why Only Germany Can Fix the Euro’ (F oreign Affairs 17 November 2011)
accessed 19 February 2013. The article b y Mark Blyth and
Matthias Matthijs quotes Kindleberger’s The World in Depression 1929-1939. The article goes on to list four
other primary reasons for the collapse of the European economy-failure to pro vide countercyclical long-term
lending, stable exchange rates, macroeconomic policy coordination, and real lending of last resort d uring
financial crises. Solving these problems are said to result in the strengthening of the European econo my.
[2013] COLR
2
thought to have retained competency.
3 The Court of Justice of the European Union
(hereinafter ‘CJEU’), in its case-law however, has sought to minimise the effect of this
constraint by successfully invoking the principle of prohibition of discrimination in direct
taxation. As Professor Pistone has noted:
‘We all know that the CJEU is trying hard to remove cross-border direct tax
obstacles, whenever they arise and whatever price we may have to pay in
terms of the structure and consistency of our national tax systems.’4
This article seeks to critically investigate the CJEU’s approach to the principle of non-
discrimination in EU Taxation Law. The analysis will demonstrate that the jurisprudence has
been primarily characterised by inconsistency, uncertainty and unpredictability. Whilst
deconstruction of the tax systems of Member States, through invocation of the principle, in
itself is unpalatable, the resulting haphazard, inconsistent and piecemeal development of the
jurisprudence on Direct Taxation is completely unacceptable.
B THE COMPETENCY OF THE CJEU IN ADJUDICATING MATTERS OF
DIRECT TAXATION
We must first briefly assess a preliminary issue, namely, the competency of the CJEU to
adjudicate matters of Direct Taxation.
Weatherill and Beaumont observed that ‘the heart of the Community is the pursuit of
economic integration. Accordingly, the heart of the substantive law of the EC treaty is the
range of provisions that prohibit the erection or maintenance of barriers to trade between
member states’.5 In order for such ‘economic integration’ to be achieved, the institutions of
the community are empowered to remove obstacles to trade.6 Against this, one area in which
the Member States are thought to have retained competence is in the area of direct tax,7 given
that taxation obstructs trade by its very nature. The CJEU has, however, ‘frequently held that
3 Discussed below.
4 Pasquale Pistone, ‘European direct tax law: quo vadis?’ in Michael Lang and Frans Vanistendael Accounting
and Taxation & Assessment of ECJ Case Law (IBFD Public ations BV 2008).
5 Stephen Weatherill and Paul Beaumont, EC Law (2nd edn, Penguin 1995) 30.
6 See Further: Paul Craig and Grainne De Burca, EU Law: Cases, Texts and Materia ls, (5th edn, OUP 2011);
Catherine Barnard, The Substantive law of the EU: The Fundamental Fr eedoms, (3rd edn, OUP 2010).
7 Christiana HJI Panayi, ‘Reverse subsidiarity and EU Tax Law: can Member States be left to their o wn
devices?’ [2010] BTR 267, 267.
[2013] COLR
3
the powers retained by the Member States must be exercised consistently with Union
8 Law‘9
which is superior to the national law of Member States as a result of the landmark cases of
Van Gend en Loos10 and Costa.11 Although Member States have retained sovereignty in
relation to Direct Tax matters, the power must not be exercised in a manner contrary to the
principles of Community Law, in which case taxation would become analogous to an
obstacle to ‘economic integration’. Thus, this article critically evaluates one such principle,
namely, the principle of prohibition of discrimination in direct taxation matters.
C DEVELOPMENT OF THE PRINCIPLE OF PROHIBITION OF
DISCRIMINATION IN DIRECT TAXATION
The basic non-discrimination principle of EU law is that EU non-nationals and non-resident
EU companies have to be treated in the host Member State in the same manner as nationals
and companies of that state.12 Different treatment of domestic source income and income
sourced in another Member State or, in general, different tax treatment of the cross-border
situation as compared to the similar domestic situation is in principle prohibited.13 Metzler14
concisely summarises the test which the CJEU employs in order to ascertain whether national
tax provisions are discriminatory. First, it determines whether or not two situations are
comparable.15 Thereafter, it determines whether the different rules apply to comparable
situations or the same rules apply to different situations.
8 Although Dr Panayi refers to ‘Community Law’, parlance amongst writers today is to refer to Union Law
given that the once separate entities of EU and the EC have now been amalgamated under the one heading,
namely, European Union Law. For a concise summary of this development, see Jones & Sufrin, EU
Competition Law (4th edn, OUP 2011) 94-95.
9 Panayi (n 7) 267.
10 NV Algemene Transporten Expeditie Onderneming van Gend en Loos v Nederlandse Administratis der
Belastingen Case 26/62 [1963] ECR 1.
11 Flaminio Costa v ENEL Case 6/64 [1964] ECR 585. Thus any provision of Member States Law which is
found to be contrary to Community Law becomes inapplicable. For further reading on concepts such as
‘Supremacy’, ‘Direct Effect’, ‘Indirect Effect’ and ‘State Liability’ see (n 7).
12 Vanessa E Metzler, ‘The Relevance of Fundamental Freedoms for Direct Taxation’, in M Lang, P Pistone, J
Schuch and C Staringer (eds), Introductio n to Europea n Tax Law: Direct Taxation (Spiramus, Biddles 2008)
44.
13 Ben Terra and Peter Wattel, Fisca le Handboeken : European Tax Law (Kluwer Law International, The
Hague, 2008) 717-718. The authors also note that measures rendering cross border activity excessively di fficult
without justification are also prohibited, citing Case C 415/93 VZW Koninklijke Belgische Voetbalbond and
others v. Jea n-Marc Bosman [1995] ECR I-4921 as evidence that even CFC rules, thin capitali sation rules,
transfer pricing documentation requirements, exclusion of cross-border lo ss relief, and in general all national tax
base conservation measures are suspect, even if they are applied indiscriminately in comparable situations.
14 Metzler (n 12) 44.
15ibid.
[2013] COLR
4
Discrimination in both the former and latter scenario
16 results in a breach of Community Law
as it infringes the Fundamental Freedoms. According to Meltzer, the classical pair of
comparison is that of a person who exercises its freedoms compared to a person who remains
in the home state. In other words, the factual cross border situation is compared with the
hypothetical situation of a taxpayer who remains in the home state.17 This is in spite of the
fact that the resident and non-resident are not, prima facie, in comparable situations.18 Under
this heading, the Court also compares the situation of a permanent establishment and a home
state company.19 Further, the court has established that residents and non residents are
entitled to the same personal and family deductions.20 Meltzer cites several other headings
under which the CJEU has interpreted the situations as being comparable.21 The heading of
cross-border situations comprises comparisons between cross border situations with national
situations and also comparisons between two cross border situations.22 Should a national tax
provision be held to fall foul of this test, it may be justified,23 but such justification is subject
to the principle of proportionality.24
The proceeding passage of this article will seek to highlight several areas in which
commentators are highly critical of the CJEU’s application of the principle. As alluded to
above, it will be argued that the application has been inconsistent, unpredictable and
uncertain.
16 Kerckhaert-Morre s [2006] ECR I-10967 [hereinafter ‘Kerckhaert’].
17 Metzler (n 12) 45.
18 ibid 46.
19 ibid 47.
20 Schumacker [1995] ECR I-225.
21 Metzler (n 12) 49-52.
22 ibid.
23 See below for the discussion on justification. As Joachim English notes, the CJEU is generally reluctant to
allow Member States to have resort to discr iminatory measures in order to counteract beneficial aspects
originating in the tax system of another Member State, even if such tax benefits can arguabl y be qualified as
unfair cf Cadbur y Schweppes plc and Cadb ury Schweppes Overseas Ltd v Commissioners of Inland Revenue
(C-196/04) [2006] ECR I-7995 (J. English ‘HMRC v Philips Electronics UK Ltd: a nother contribution to EU
law jurisprudence on loss relief’ [2012] BTR 586 (n 73).) See also DMMA Arens -Sikken v Staatssecretaris van
Financiën (C-43/07) [2008] ECR I-6887 [66]; Amurta SGPS v Inspecteur van de Belastingdienst/ Amsterdam
(C-379/05) [2007] ECR I-9569; [2008] STC 2851 (Amurta) [78] et seq.; Hans Eckelkamp and Others v Belgia n
State (C-11/07) [2008] ECR I-6845 [69].
24 See below for the discussion on the principle proportionality.
[2013] COLR
5
D CRITICAL DISCUSSION OF THE CJEU’S APPLICATION OF THE
PRINCIPLE OF NON-DISCRIMINATION
1 The Shift in Terminology
Commentators have noted that there has been a marked transition in the terminology used in
relation to Direct Tax cases. Snell
25 notes that the Court has started to use language which
mirrors its terminology used in the field of regulatory barriers to free movements. Early cases
of the CJEU in tax matters were decided on the basis of the discrimination test outlined
above. In Bachmann,26 the CJEU held that the difference in treatment of tax deductions for
insurance premiums constituted unlawful discrimination between nationals and non-
nationals. However, the court later abandoned the language of discrimination in direct tax
case law, first seen in Futura Participations.27 The full court stated that Luxembourg’s rule
on accounts amounted to a ‘restriction’28 and was prohibited ‘as it specifically affected
companies having their seat in another Member State’.29 The same ‘restrictions’ terminology
was also utilised in Safir30 and Verkooijen.31
Snell argues, however, that there is no actual shift in judicial thinking; that the test is still one
based on discrimination and that substantive obstacle-based analysis has not been engaged
with in relation to Direct Taxation by the CJEU. Whilst the terminology employed is the
same as that language used in the obstacle-orientated jurisprudence developed in a regulatory
context, Snell contends the reality is that judicial thought continues in its more restrictive
discrimination based approach.32 He states33 that there have been cases where the Court has
allowed national tax rules to stand in the absence of discrimination without examining
whether they might constitute a barrier.34
In spite of Snell’s attestations, this author opines that there is an argument to be made that the
shift is more than merely apparent and has in reality led to inconsistency in the case-law. In
25 Jukka Snell, ‘Non discriminatory tax obstacles in Community Law’ (2007) ICLQ 339, 349.
26 Case C-204/90, Bachmann v. Belgium [hereinafter ‘Bachmann’].
27 Case C-250/95 Futur a Productions [1997] ECR I-1247 1. [hereinafter ‘Futur a Productions’].
28 ibid [24].
29 ibid [26].
30 Case C-118/96 Safir [1998] ECR I-1897.
31 Case C-35/98 Verkooijen [2000] ECR I-4071 [hereinafter ‘Verkooijen’].
32 Snell (n 25) 350.
33 ibid.
34 ibid.
[2013] COLR
6
Bosal,
35 the court found a breach of Article 49 TFEU due to its assessment that a Dutch tax
rule ‘might dissuade a parent company from carrying on its activities in another Member
State’. 36 According to Barnard, 37 State Treasuries expressed grave concern about the
implication of the Court’s ‘restrictions’ analysis as the case cost the Dutch Treasuries
millions. Such a result renders it difficult to concur entirely with Snell’s assertion that the
shift has been merely cosmetic.
The shift therefore is worrying for Member States as it purports to import into EU Law a
much lower barrier for what kind of tax measure will be constituted as an infringement of the
Treaties. Given that virtually all national tax provisions would constitute an ‘obstacle’ under
the restrictions analysis, it is argued that this shift may be a source of further confusion for
Member States. The initial confusion, as Panayi notes, is a direct result of ‘Reverse
Subsidiarity’; ‘a situation whereby, in exercising their technically exclusive powers, Member
States find themselves significantly constrained by EU Law’. 38
In brief, the shift in judicial thinking, whether actual or cosmetic, leads to a situation wherein
Member States are uncertain as to the balance between their sovereignty in Direct Tax
Matters and the competency of CJEU.
2 Instances of Inconsistency, Unpredictability and Uncertainty
First; Panayi39 argues that there has been a ‘patchwork’ application by the CJEU of the non-
discrimination principle which has led to inequality of treatment between Member States.
Following the judgment of the CJEU in Marks & Spencers,40 the UK was required to amend
its existing legislation in order to grant relief for terminal losses. However, countries such as
Finland or the Netherlands are not required to include such losses as a result of their fiscal
35 Bosal Holding BV v. Staatsecretar is van F inancien [2003] ECR I-9409.
36 ibid.
37 Catherine Barnard ‘Restricting restrictions: lessons for the EU from the US?’ (2009 ) 68(3) CLJ 575, 600.
38 Panayi (n 7) 267.
39 ibid 300.
40 Marks & Spencers plc v. Halsey (Inspector of Taxes) (C-446/03) [2005] ECR I-10837.
[2013] COLR
7
unity regime.
41 In this instance, inconsistent application of the non-discrimination principle42
has clearly led to inequality between states.43
Second; whilst Snell might not acknowledge an actual shift in judicial thinking, the learned
professor does accept that there has been an unacceptable level of unpredictability and
uncertainty in the case-law in relation to three main defences44 put forward by Member States
to justify discriminatory direct tax provisions: Reciprocity, Territoriality and Fiscal
Competence. The acceptance of such defences in Taxation Law stands in direct contrast to
their dismissal in other matters of EU Law.
The Reciprocity argument, that mutual exchange of privileges between Member States are
permissible in the absence of conflict with Union Law, pivots on the basis that privileges are
not discriminatory against non-residents of one country but rather are advantageous for non-
residents of another country.45 Such reciprocal, preferable treatment has been accepted in D46
as being distinguished from discrimination. 47 Tax allowances for Dutch residents were
extended to Belgians by virtue of a bilateral tax convention. The court rejected the argument
that the resulting difference in treatment between Belgian and German residents amounted to
discrimination. The Court stated that ‘reciprocal rights and obligations apply only to persons
resident in one of the two contracting Member States as an inherent consequence of bilateral
taxation conventions’.48 This treatment of the reciprocity argument stands in direct contrast
with the judgment in Matteucci,49 notwithstanding the fact that the case concerned a bilateral
cultural agreement rather than a tax treaty. The court there held that the bilateral agreement
cannot preclude the application of Community rules on equal treatment. Snell argues that the
contrast displays a shift in emphasis towards a more favourable treatment of reciprocity in
41 X Holding C-337/08. The Netherlands allows liquidation losses of domestic and foreign subsidiaries to be
surrendered to the Dutch parent company.
42 In applying to one country but not to another in the same scenario.
43 Panayi (n 7) 300. Panayi further states that the situation is exacerbated by the fact that i n some countries, tax
payers and national courts are more familiar with EU Law than in other countries. Legislation in these countries
gets struck down or removed more frequently. The author then asks the question whether this means that some
Member States are penalised for their pro-activeness and ultimate commitment to the EU wherea s others are
indirectly rewarded for their inactivity, intransigence and potential illegality.
44 Snell (n 25) 350.
45 As per Advocate-General Ruiz-Jarabo, [101], the argument will be accepted subject to the satisfaction of two
criteria. First, in setting in those agreements the criteria for allocating competence in taxation matters, the
Member States must act with the utmost care, avoiding any provisions which might hi nder that objective (of
establishing the single market). Second, the right to equal treatment stands alone and is independent from the
principle of reciprocity and therefore, in the event of a conflict, it takes precedence over mutu al commitments.
46 Case C-376/03 D [2005] ECR I-5821.
47 The ruling in Case C-374/04 ACT Group Litigation [2006] ECR I-0000 confirmed the judgment.
48 D case (n 46) [61].
49 Case 235/87 Matteucci [1988] ECR 5589.
[2013] COLR
8
bilateral tax conventions. Professor Van Thiel is even more equivocal
50 in his criticism of this
inconsistency in the law,51 citing the considerable potential for distortion of the optimal
allocation of resources on the European internal market. The learned Professor submits that
such distortion flows from allowing a different tax treatment by one host Member State of
two identical incoming capital flows from two different home Member States, on the sole
ground that it is treaty-based.52
Snell provides further examples of this unpredictability and uncertainty in relation to the
treatment of the principle of Territor iality. This principle states generally that each state taxes
only such income of a non-resident that has a connection with its territory.53 In other words, a
taxpayer participating in economic intercourse in the domestic territory is only taxed on his
profits and losses generated in the domestic territory.54 Snell convincingly contrasts the
favourable treatment in Futura P articipations of the territoriality principle in a fiscal context
with that of the treatment of the same principle in Musik,55 albeit in a regulatory context. 56
Finally, Snell further demonstrates inconsistency in the jurisprudence by citing the principle
of Fiscal Competence. This argument centres on the premise that, in the absence of EU
harmonising measures, Member States are competent to determine criteria for taxation with a
view to eliminating double taxation by way of, inter alia, bi-lateral agreements.57 In Gilly,58
the court drew a distinction between the allocation and exercise of fiscal competence. It was
thereafter held that the use of national criterion in the allocation of Fiscal Competence did not
amount to unlawful discrimination on the grounds of nationality. Such an argument however
was expressly rejected in the regulatory context in Van Hilten.59
Snell’s analysis displays instances where discrimination is distinguished in Direct Tax
matters but is categorically rejected in the regulatory context. Accordingly, it is quite logical
for Snell to conclude that this differing treatment of the same arguments has led to an
50 See also: Axel Cordewener and Ekkehart Reimer, ‘The future of most-favoured -nation treatment in EC tax
law--Did the ECJ pull the emergency break without real need?--Part 2 ’ (2006) 46 ET 291.
51 Servaas van Thiel, ‘A slip of the European Court in the D case (C-376/03): d enial of the most favoured-nation
treatment because of absence of similarity?’ (2005) 33 Intertax 454, 455 -7.
52 ibid.
53 Marjaana Helminen, EU Tax Law Direct Taxation (2nd edn, Amsterdam: IBFD 2011 ) 134.
54 Andreas Geiger and Thorsten Fischer ‘The clash of EU law and national direc t tax laws example: Germany’
(2005) ICCLR 328, 333.
55 Joined cases 55 and 57/80 Musik-Vertrieb Membran [1981] ECR 147.
56 Snell (n 25) 352.
57 Gilly (n 58) 609-610.
58 Case C-336/96 Gilly [1998] ECR I-2793.
59 Case C-513/03 Van Hilten-van der Heijden [2006] ECR I-1957.
[2013] COLR
9
unacceptable level of unpredictability and uncertainty. The critical importance of such
matters in tax law gives extra weight to this argument. As Advocate General Geelhoed has
noted, ‘predictability and certainty are crucial’
60 in tax law as Member States need to be able
to plan their budgets and design their tax systems on the basis of relatively reliable revenue
predictions.
The justification by way of the Fiscal Cohesion argument is often cited61 as another instance
of inconsistency in the application by the CJEU of the non-discrimination principle. This
concept concerns cohesion between tax base reductions (or unrealised gains) and
corresponding base increases (or realisation, respectively) within the same taxing
jurisdiction.62 In Bachmann, a German national, employed in Belgium, was not allowed to
deduct contributions paid in Germany for various insurance and assurance policies from his
total occupational income. Such contributions paid in Belgium were deductible. The Court
accepted the inherent discrimination could be justified by the cohesion of the Belgian
national tax system. The dismissal of the fiscal cohesion argument in the subsequent cases of
Baars63 and Verkooijien64 led academics such as Snell to conclude that the defence had been
rendered largely redundant. Advocates General Kokott,65 Polares Maduro66 and Stix Hackl67
moreover had called for its rehabilitation. It has been assumed that this justification had
essentially been distinguished out of existence on the basis that there must be a direct link
between the deductibility of contributions and the liability to tax payments.68
It must be noted that a justification for a discriminatory taxation measure will only be
accepted if it does not go beyond what is necessary to achieve its purpose and aim.69 An
example of the application of this principle of proportionality can be found in F utura
Pa rticipations, 70 the court accepted Luxembourg’s justification on the basis of Fiscal
Supervision. However, it was held that it would be disproportionate to ask the French
company involved to keep separate records. The main criticism of the proportionality
60 Case C-374/04 ACT Group Litigation [2006] ECR I-0000 [hereinafter ‘ACT Group Litigation’].
61 Mattias Dahlberg, Direct Taxation in Rela tion to the Freedom of Establishment and the F ree Movement of
Capital, (Kluwer Law International, The Hague 2005) 119-124.
62 Terra and Wattel (n 13) 761.
63 Case C-251/98 Baar s [2000] ECR I-2787.
64 See also, Cases C-80/94 (Wielockx), C-168/01 (Bosal Holding).
65 Case C-319/02 Mannimen [2004]ECR I-7477.
66 Case C-446/03 Marks and Spencer [20 05] ECR I-10837.
67 Case C-150/04 Commission v Denmark [2006] ECR I-6435.
68 Metzler (n 12) 54.
69 ibid 64.
70 See also Case C-436/00 X and Y [2002] ECR I-10829 [49].
[2013] COLR
principle generally lies in its subjectivity. What may seem proportionate to one judge may be
disproportionate to another judge. Dr. Gerard Hogan
71 cites several cases 72 which
demonstrate the inconsistent application of the principle, sometimes even in relation to the
same case, resulting in wildly differing conclusions.
3 Recent Trends
Recent case-law however suggests that the CJEU may finally have found a coherent course
of action in relation to justifications and is now less systematic in dismissing the defences of
Member States, at least in relation to the manner in which the CJEU now deals with the
Taxing Power defence of Member States. This pivots on the need to preserve the allocation
of powers of taxation between Member States. A Member State’s power of taxation is
impaired if losses incurred within the scope of the exclusive power of taxation of another
Member State are required to be taken into account.73
The initial inconsistency in the law stems from the fallout of the Marks case.74 As noted by
Advocate General Kokott, the name Marks & Spencer had been interpreted as being
‘synonymous with chaos and despair’.75 This ‘chaos and despair’ flowed from the CJEU’s
discussion of the Taxing Power justification. The Court here found that there was a restriction
on the Freedom of Establishment, running contrary to the principle against discrimination.76
Following the finding, the CJEU argued that the restriction could be justified on the basis of
three grounds,77 taken together:78 First, the need to preserve the allocation of taxing rights
between Member States;79 Second, the need to prevent the relief of losses in both the
71Gerald Hogan ‘The Constitution, Property Rights and Proportionality’ (1997) 32(1) JUR 373, 390 -392.
72 Air Canada v. United Kingdom (1995) 20 EHRR 150 and Bhosphorus Ha va Yollari Turizm Ve Tickaret
Anonim Sirekti v. Minister for Transpor t [1994] 2 ILRM 551.
73 Case C-18/11 HMRC v. Philips Electronics U. K. Ltd [2012] ECR I-0000 (hereinafter ‘Philips Electronics’)
[50] (Kokott AG).
74 Marks & Spencer plc v Halsey (Inspector of Taxes) (C-446/03) [2005] ECR I-10837 (hereinafter ‘Marks’).
75 C-123/11, A Oy (judgment pending, Opinion of the Advocate General Kokott of 19 July 2012) (hereinafter A
Oy’) [1].
76 For a succinct explanation of the interaction between the Freedom of Establishment under Articles 49 and 5 4
TFEU and the principle against discrimination, see P hilips, (n 74) [24]: ‘Article [49 TFEU] expressly leaves
traders free to choose the appropriate legal form in which to pursue their activities in a nother Member State, that
freedom of choice must not be limited by discriminatory tax provisions in the host Member State’ (Kokott AG).
77 The succinct enumeration of these three grounds is taken from Panayi (n 7) 278.
78 Marks (n 74) [51].
79 ibid [43]-[46].
[2013] COLR
Member State of the subsidiary and the Member State of the parent company;
80 Third, the
need to prevent tax avoidance.81
Two primary questions arose from the ashes of the Marks judgement. The first was whether
there was in fact a need for the presence of all three criteria in order to satisfy the Taxing
Power exception. In Oy AA,82 the Court recognised that a justification is possible through the
two elements of safeguarding the allocation of the power to tax between the Member States
and the need to prevent tax avoidance.83 Subsequently, in Lidl Belgium84 it also accepted a
justification solely on the basis of the allocation of the power to tax between the Member
States and the danger that the same losses will be taken into account twice.85
The Court examined and accepted the justification on this singular basis also in National
Grid Indus.86In Philips Electronics, a UK company (Philips Electronics) was the parent of a
Dutch-resident company (NL Co). NL Co indirectly owned LGPD Netherlands, which had a
loss-making permanent establishment in the UK (UK PE). Philips Electronics wanted to use
UK PE’s losses to be set off against its own profits. This was refused by the HMRC as a
result of the fact that those losses could also be used against profits in the Netherlands (by NL
Co). According to UK tax law, the offsetting of such losses would have been permissible if
incurred by a UK resident, rather than the UK branch of a non-resident. The Court
established that the UK provision constituted a restriction to the freedom of establishment,
holding that the difference in treatment between resident and non-resident companies could
not be justified on the basis that the companies were not in comparable positions, as
evidenced by objective elements.87 The Court then turned to a possible justification of the
restriction by virtue of the Taxing Power defence. The CJEU found that the UK was the
Taxing Power and, following the Advocate General’s opinion, thusly rejected the argument
80 ibid [47]-[48].
81 ibid [49]-[50].
82 Case C-231/05 Oy AA [2007] ECR I-6373 [60].
83 (n 73) [41] (Kokott AG).
84 See also, N v Inspecteur van de Belastingdienst Oost/kantoor Almelo (C-470/04) [2006] ECR I-7409 [42];
Proceedin gs brought by Oy AA (Oy AA) (C-231/05) [2007] ECR I-6373 [51]-[60]; Amurta SGPS v Inspecteur
van de Belastingdienst/Amsterdam (C-379/05) [2007] ECR I-9569 [ 57]-[59].
85 (n 73) [41] (Kokott AG).
86 Case C-371/10 National Gr id Indus [2011] ECR I-0000, [45]-[49]; Case C-470/04 N [2006] ECR I-7409 [42].
87 Philips (n 74) 221.
[2013] COLR
that the denial of group relief could be justified on the grounds of preservation of a balanced
allocation of taxing powers.
88
Following this trend of jurisprudence, it has now been firmly established that the second and
third criterion of Marks, preventing the double use of losses and tax avoidance, do not
constitute an end in themselves, but are relevant only in so far as they serve to preserve the
allocation of the power to tax between the Member States.89 Therefore it is clear that the
crucial factor for the justification is ultimately that national legislation pursues the objective
of preserving the allocation of the Taxing Power. 90 Such coherency is a welcome
development to an area of law which has been primarily typified by inconsistency,
uncertainty and unpredictability.
The second issue related to the scope of the exception to the taxing power justification, in
other words, the requirement to offset such losses against which there was no other recourse.
This exception was laid down in Marks where the Court found that the Taxing Power
restriction also had to be proportional. As per Panayi, it was only when the resident parent
company demonstrated to the tax authorities of its Member State that all possibilities for
relief had been exhausted that it became contrary to freedom of establishment to preclude the
possibility for the parent company to deduct from its taxable profits in that Member State the
losses incurred by its non-resident subsidiary.91
In A Oy,92 at issue was the allowing the losses of a foreign company, this time in the context
of a merger. A Finnish company wanted to merge with a Swedish subsidiary. There were 3
retail companies in Sweden with losses of about €5 m. Finnish tax law prevented the Finnish
company from taking into account those losses upon the merger. According to Kokott, this
was a restriction of the freedom of establishment. The question was then whether there was a
possible justification. The Advocate General focused on whether the Taxing Power
justification would be proportional. The case was distinguished from Mar ks on the basis that,
in the within case, there was a choice on the part of the Swedish taxpayer.93 In Marks, the
subsidiary in Europe was in liquidation, thus leaving the company no avenue to offset the
losses in the State with the Taxing Power. In A Oy however, the Swedish partner could have
88 ibid 226.
89 Case C-311/08 SGI [2010] ECR I-487 [59] (Kokott AG).
90 (n 74) [42] (Kokott AG).
91 Panayi (n 7) 278-279.
92(n 75) (Kokott AG).
93 ibid.
[2013] COLR
decided to continue trading. Therefore, the Advocate General recommended a finding that the
Finnish tax measure was justifiable to preserve the taxing power of Finland.
94 The opinion is
seen to limit the Marks exception to its own exceptional facts wherein the European
subsidiary company had no recourse in the Taxing Power State to offset the losses. Following
the opinion of the Advocate General, as this author expects,95 will bring further clarity to this
issue.
In brief summation, the recent case-law suggests that the chaos and despair caused by the
Marks judgment has finally been laid to rest, resulting in a welcome coherency in relation to
the Taxing Power defence.
E ACADEMIC COMMENTARY ON THE PRINCIPLE
It is quite clear that the CJEU has applied quite inconsistently the principle of prohibition of
discrimination to direct taxation measures, notwithstanding the argument that the Court may
finally have found a coherent path for determination of whether Justifications by Member
States will absolve discriminatory taxation approaches. There is no shortage of academic
commentary to criticise the court in this respect. It is interesting to consider the reasons for
the seeming inability of the Court to find a steady course of action in this area of law.
First, the CJEU is not a specialised Tax Court.96 Therefore, it may lack expertise, depending
on the judges appointed to the bench at a particular time and sitting in a particular case.97
Second, Emer Hunt98 concludes that there is an underlying tension between a national tax
system based on residence and the impact of the fundamental freedoms on residence as a
determinant of liability. The status quo arises as a result of political sensitivity99 in relation to
fiscal issues. The power to tax is a power of the State to coercively raise revenue. This forms
a fundamental part of State sovereignty. At one extreme, it allows the State to accumulate
resources in preparation for a period of ‘State Emergency’, such as war. On the other end, the
power to tax is a central instrument of economic and social policy. For example, ‘tax breaks’
94 ibid.
95 Such an assertion is based on the fact that Advocate General Kokott’s opinions on matters of Direct T axation
have been consistently followed. For instance, see the aforementioned Philips and SGI cases.
96 Snell (n 25) 369.
97 PJ Wattel, ‘Red Herrings in Direct Tax Cases Before the ECJ’ (2004) 31 LIEI 81, 82.
98 E. Hunt ‘What Can be Done? The Tax Wars Between Member States and the CJEU’ (2004) 17(1) ITR 77, 79.
99 See: Inland Revenue PN06, issued 9th April, 2003 wherein it was stated that ‘The Go vernment is determined
to protect his corporation tax system against legal challenges under European law, particularly where these
challenges have the potential to undermine international agreements’.
[2013] COLR
were offered to Irish companies establishing themselves in Templebar in Dublin in order to
encourage tourism.
100 Another reason for this tension results from the fact that regulation and
taxation pursue fundamentally different objectives. Regulation is largely about economic
efficiency, thereby rectifying market failures no more than necessary, whereas Tax rules are
essential elements in the redistribution of wealth.101Third, Snell points out that as long as the
fundamental ambiguity about the nature of the single market persists, whether the goal is a
common market or an internal market, the Court will struggle to achieve coherence in its
case-law:
[i]f the aim is the common market, a patchwork of highly dissimilar national
tax regimes is difficult to tolerate. By contrast, the internal market is
favourably disposed towards differing national rules as long as they do not
constitute barriers.102
Notwithstanding the aforementioned problems relating to its application, the literature does
attest to the merit of retaining the principle within EU Taxation Law. First, discriminatory
rules are considered unlawful because they allow irrelevant factors to be taken into account
(e.g. the need to protect the insider from the outsider)103. Account for such irrelevant factors
runs contrary to the concept of the Union and undermines the solidarity between the
constituent elements of the polity.104 Second, discrimination and protectionism are inefficient
criteria because they divert ‘business away from presumptively low-cost [foreign] producers
[to high-cost (local) producers] without any colourable justification in terms of benefit that
deserves approval from the point of view of the nation as a whole’.105 A third rationale, and
one strongly pushed by Justice Stone in the 1930s in the US, concerns the operation of the
political process:106 Although pre-dating the existence of the EU, the argument pertains
relevance to the matter at hand. Community Law should be used to invalidate discriminatory
state rules. National Rules, as with state rules, are the product of a successfully functioning
democratic process operating at national level. Where discriminatory rules are produced in
the process, the party most affected (i.e. the non-national) is not represented. Fourth, the great
advantage of the principle is that it leaves room for state action, largely unhindered by
100 Snell (n 25) 355.
101 ibid 355-356.
102 ibid 368.
103 Barnard (n 37) 581.
104 ibid.
105 ibid.
106 ibid.
[2013] COLR
concerns that the Commission or European Courts will intervene: ‘State rules can therefore
respond to the demands of the local electorate, so long as that electorate does not insist on
discriminatory rules being put into place’.
107 Furthermore, this results in a diversity of rules
across the Member States which leaves room for experimentation; experimentation from
which the other States can learn. 108 Finally, the merit of applying such a principle is
evidenced by the fact that the similarly structured United States 109 also applies the
Discrimination principle, subject to one minor proviso. It is prudent at this juncture to briefly
outline the manifestation of the principle in US Tax Law. The ‘Commerce Clause’110 states
that ‘The Congress shall have Power...to regulate Commerce with foreign Nations and among
the several States...’ This gives the federal government the power to legislate in respect of
commerce, although it does not prohibit state-created restrictions on inter-state commerce.111
Facially discriminatory and discriminatory in effect 112 statutes are subject to a ‘strict
scrutiny’ review113 which essentially means that the court checks whether the statute serves ‘a
legitimate local purpose’ and 114 whether there is an ‘absence of non-discriminatory
alternatives’.115 Therefore, the US approach essentially mirrors the EU approach to direct
taxation matters. In both instances, discriminatory taxation provisions are prima facie
unlawful unless they can be justified (the EU model), or they give effect to ‘legitimate local
purposes’ (the US Model) and are not disproportionate to the desired object (the EU Model)
or absent of ‘non-discriminatory alternatives’ (the US model). Where this becomes
interesting, is in relation to double taxation. Essentially, the US Supreme Court has
interpreted the Commerce Clause as prohibiting cumulative tax burdens that would expose
businesses active in interstate trade to a higher tax burden than those operating in a single
state.116 Justice Stone feared the multiplication of State taxes burdening the same activity
‘would spell the destruction of inter-state commerce’.117 However, the CJEU in Kerckhaert118
107 ibid.
108 ibid.
109 Any discussion of the Substantive Law of the EU would be incomplete without reference to the United
States. The inclusion is justified given the comparable structure of Federal Laws superseding S tate Law just as
EU Law is supreme to National Laws, whilst conversely each state has autonomy to determine its own la ws
provided these do not conflict with the overriding Federal or Union Law.
110 United States Constitution (Article I, Section 8, Clause 3).
111 Barnard (n 37) 585.
112 There is case law to suggest, however, that these statutes are subjected to a more relaxed standard -Dean Milk
v Madison 340 US 349 (1951).
113 Hughes v. Oklahoma 441 US 322, 337 (1979).
114 Both limbs are required: City of Philadelphia v. New Jersey 437 US 617, 626 (1978).
115 Chemical Waste Management Inc v. Hunt 504 US 334, 342-3 (1992).
116 Snell (n 25) 360.
117 Western Live Stock v Bureau of Revenue 303 US 250 (1938) 256.
[2013] COLR
held that double taxation does not fall foul of the discrimination principle provided that it is
applied in an even handed fashion. Thus, it may be said that the application of the principle in
the US runs parallel to the application by its EU counterpart, albeit, with the potential for
catching infringements which fall beyond the parameters of the pure discrimination test.
Thus, it is rational to summate that the discrimination principle does indeed have a ‘good and
well-respected pedigree’.
119 The conclusion to be drawn from the above discussion must,
however, be that the application in practice by the CJEU of the principle unfortunately leaves
a lot to be desired. The literature presents cogent reasons as to why such misapplication has
inevitably occurred. Moreover, the literature asks serious questions as to whether the CJEU is
indeed the appropriate forum to determine Union-wide taxation matters.
F CONCLUSION
This critical discussion of the application by the CJEU of the principle of non-discrimination
in Direct Taxation matters has pragmatically laid out the unacceptable flaws in the CJEU
case-law. The marked shift in terminology has not only led to unpredictability and
uncertainty but there is also merit in the proposition that the shift has resulted in
inconsistency. Moreover, the treatment by the CJEU of cross border schemes has resulted in
inequality of treatment between EU Member States. Serious questions have also been asked
of the CJEU’s application of the principle in relation to justifications. It has been found that
the jurisprudential development to date has been characterised by inconsistency, uncertainty
and unpredictability. However, recent trends might lead one to tentatively summate that there
is a possibility that the CJEU may reign in these flaws of application. Nevertheless, the
fundamental importance of ‘certainty and predictability’ in taxation matters 120 overall
renders the CJEU’s application of the principle unacceptable. Several reasons have been cited
for the development whilst the merit of the principle itself has concurrently been outlined.
118 Case C-513/04. The case concerned a blanket Belgia n tax of 25 per cent imposed on all dividends, regardless
of source. The Kerckhaerts, two Belgian residents, received dividends from a French company which had
already been subjected to a 15 per cent withholding levy in France. The dividends were then taxed by the
relevant Belgian authorities. The Grand Chamber of the court, concurring with Advocate General Geelhoed,
rejected the Kerckhaerts argument that the double taxation violated (then) article 56 EC on free movement of
capital. This case was later followed by the Grand Chamber of the Court in ACT Group Litigation C-446/0,
again following Advocate General Geelhoed, holding that a home state is free to impo se a second tax regardless
of what the source State has done. Furthermore, the source state is not obliged to provide relief in cross -border
situations, even if it does grant such relief internally.
119 Barnard (n 37) 581.
120 As noted above by Geelhoed AG.
[2013] COLR
But should we be surprised at the above conclusions, given that Advocate General Geelhoed
once opined that ‘judicial intervention, by its very nature, is casuistic and fragmented’?
121
The opening paragraph alluded to the concept that further integration of the internal market is
of fundamental importance going forward. What is required is an impenetrable and
comprehensive reformulation of the principle which provides certainty for the Member
States’ judiciary, legislature and taxpayers.122 This, it is suggested, will result in uniformity
across the 27 Member States. In this manner, the obstructive effect of national direct taxation
measures could be limited to the furthest extent possible. Given the economic climate and the
unacceptable CJEU jurisprudential development to date, the author posits that the legislative
pen123 is required to be the paramount, omnipotent arbitrator in the pursuance of certainty in
direct taxation matters and concurrently, the illusive single market.
121 ACT Group Litigation [39].
122 A detailed discussion of this option is beyond the scope of this essay. The author suggests however that the
Commission ought to produce a comprehensive report outlining precisely the scope of the principle. Such has
had the effect in the analogous arena of EU Insolvency Law, through the Virgo-Schmidt Report, of significantly
clarifying the law and providing uniformity.
123 Whether by way of regulation, directive or Commission report. There is evidence to suggest that the
legislative intervention is already attempting to combat the shortfalls in the market. For example, the
Commission has been eager to establish a Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base. The European
Commission on 16 March 2011 proposed a common system for calculatin g the tax base of businesses operating
in the EU. The proposed Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCTB), would mean that co mpanies
would benefit from a ‘one-stop-shop’ system for filing their tax returns and would be able to co nsolidate all the
profits and losses they incur across the EU. See: P roposal for a Council Dir ective on a Common Consolidated
Corpora te Tax Base at accessed 19 February 2013.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT